This work is available here free,
so that
those who cannot afford it can still have access to it, and so that
no one has to pay before they read something that might not be what
they really are seeking. But if you find it meaningful and helpful
and would like to contribute whatever
easily affordable amount you feel it is worth, please do do. I
will appreciate it. The button to the right will take you to
PayPal where you can make any size donation you
wish, using either your PayPal account
or a credit card without a PayPal account.
|
|
Pandemics and Economics
Rick Garlikov
As the coronavirus COVID-19 pandemic has grown in
America and throughout the world, articles about the economic problems
and proposed fixes for them have started to appear and multiply.
Here I want to put into a broader philosophical and ethical perspective
the economics of pandemics. Many economists have the specifics
correct, but there is more to it than those specifics. And it is
particularly important to understand all this now because many
people are more fearful about the economy than is necessary and because
arguments are starting to appear from politicians that we are allegedly
going to have to choose between saving lives and saving the economy, and
that saving the economy is more important. President Trump has
started to complain that we can't just close down the economy of the
country, and Lt. Gov. Dan Patrick of Texas is reported
to have said grandparents like him would be willing to risk dying
from the pandemic instead of sacrificing their grandchildren's economic
future by a long term shutdown of the economy. I want to show that
is a false dilemma and that the long term economy is not at risk from
any necessary shutdown that
saves lives, if reasonable monetary or financial actions are
taken. Wrongful economic actions however can wreak more havoc and
also be extremely unfair. The initial bailout corona plan by the
U.S. Senate seems to be both insufficiently helpful and also unfair,
which is not a good combination.
In my free online book Ethical and Philosophical Foundations of Economics,
I explain that economic systems are ways to try to maximize the
availability of necessary and desired products and labor in, ideally (but not often or always in practice), the fairest
and most reasonable ways through everyone’s trading with each other (an
excess of) what they can produce. For any given amount of work
that needs to be done, generally the more people who contribute to doing
it by being a part of the economic system, either 1) the less each person has to do and
the more leisure everyone can have and/or 2) the more conveniences and luxuries
can be produced along with the necessities. All
else being equal, a larger or expanded economy has more people in the
economic (i.e., working and trading) system, and makes available more
goods, services, and/or leisure. Oppositely, in a shrunken or
contracted economic system, there are fewer people working and thus
there is less goods, services, or leisure. But it will likely not
always be the case that "all else is equal", and I will discuss some of
the relevant ramifications of that near the end of this
essay.
Wars,
natural disasters, and other large scale emergencies disrupt trade and
economic systems, often in uneven ways by putting some people, but not others, out of work, and expose and magnify problems
that are often ignored or dismissed when they occur on a smaller scale
or affect only a relative few people whose ‘loss to overall trade’ is
considered (often mistakenly) to be insignificant. Pandemics
are one kind of disruption of trade and the economic system, though
with a particular feature that makes them different from other
disruptions. Apart from the people who are actually harmed by the
diseases and those who depend on their work, pandemics also (and often
mostly) affect (i.e.,
hinder or prevent) work that involves people congregating together
in
proximity or enclosed spaces where disease-causing microbes or other
kinds of toxins can be transmitted. And they do this on a
wider scale,
and in a longer lasting time-frame, than does something like a
tornado, flood, or earthquake which physically prevent people from
getting together for a short period of time in a specific
geographical
location, but often leave the rest of the economy and trade in a larger
area, such as a state or country, able to function and also to lend
assistance. Like
any natural disaster, deadly pandemics disrupt trade by killing or disabling
people they come into direct contact with. But the prevention of
the spread of pandemics for which there is not yet a vaccine or reliable
predictability of who is at risk, requires social isolation or social
distancing -- to keep people from spreading the disease exponentially --
and so it also indirectly
disrupts businesses that require workers or customers /consumers
to congregate, even when there are no physical barriers (such as flood
water, impassable roads due to earthquake, large fires, etc.) to prevent
their getting together: sporting events in large arenas, particularly
enclosed
ones, commercial airlines, subways, buses, factories,
schools/classrooms, theaters, restaurants, etc. This prevents even
currently healthy, able, mobile workers from doing jobs that require
contact
with people who might be or become infected. They affect less, or not
at all, work that can be done in relative isolation, even if requiring
collaboration -- online teaching and learning or any other work that can
be done remotely (via Internet or by phone, mail, shipping, etc.),
television and streaming services, outdoor work not done in that close
proximity to others, automated work, etc. And they don't affect workers
who are immunized by vaccine or from any naturally acquired antibodies
from previously having the disease.
Social distancing
to prevent spread of a
deadly or
disabling disease takes out all but the most necessary non-immune
workers who work in close proximity with others from the economic
system, and thus many people without the
disease are still unable to work. That creates a trade or economic
problem over and above any physically caused shortages of goods or
services due to actually ill (or dead) workers or impossible travel
conditions. And it makes it
appear necessarily to harm the economy as the price of stopping
contagion and saving
lives. I want to address the economics part and argue that social
distancing that disrupts commerce does not have to ruin the economy for
future generations or even for the current generation during the
shutdown, but first it also needs to be pointed out that if a pandemic
is both extremely contagious and also very deadly, ending social
distancing would kill a whole lot more people and still potentially ruin
the economy
for future generations. Ending social distancing while a pandemic is
still growing or able to reinvigorate will likely not save
the economy as intended. And it is unnecessary to end it in order
to save the economy. The apparent choice between social
distancing in the United States today to save lives and ending social
distancing to save the economy, is a false dichotomy, a false dilemma,
and an unnecessary choice.
If pandemics or other disruptions to the economy affected everyone
reasonably proportionally, fewer adjustments would have to be
made than
in the normal case where some kinds of work are disrupted (far more than
others) and where some is not disrupted at all. Apart from people
who are incapacitated or killed by the illness, people whose jobs can
be done in
isolation or by telecommunication can continue to work. And people
whose work does require proximity of workers or customers, but which
though desirable and helpful, is not necessary for other people's
survival, can be dispensed with until after the danger passes -- except
that since they will still have expenses, but no usual source of income
(unless they can adapt to do work that can continue), they either need
to be provided money somehow or provided necessary goods and services
for less or free. People whose
work is unnecessary and unable to be continued in a group with the
advent of social distancing, will need to
be supported in a way that lets them meet their expenses insofar as they
don't have savings they can fall back on -- either 1) by
reducing, eliminating, or putting on hold in an affordable way,
payments for those expenses, or 2) by giving them sufficient income to
meet them. I will be arguing there is sufficient money available
to do either or both those things and that is why the economy need not
be in the kind of dire circumstances it may seem, and may not require
the kinds of sacrifice some believe. It is the disruption of
incomes and bills or expenditures, particularly in uneven, unequal, or
disproportionate ways that causes the economic problems in society over
and above whatever material or physical shortages are caused. But
there are possible ways to deal with the disrupted incomes and monetary
flow interruption effectively and fairly when
the problem is fully understood.
Because economic
disruptions force people out of the economic system, the number
of
people in the system shrinks or contracts, and that causes there to be fewer goods
and services available (or less leisure available), and available to
fewer people (and the 'economy' is said to have contracted). As
long as the curtailed or lost goods and services are not necessities,
the
people still working can survive just fine on those which are available, though maybe less happily,
in a contracted or shrunk, less productive, economy, but the people cast
out of work by the disruption need help because they still need money
(or other way to trade) to
survive unless they are self sufficient in some way (like farmers
possibly). Even though they
don't get to make a normal daily contribution or receive benefits tied
to a job, they still need money to survive till they can earn it
themselves by returning into the economic
process as soon as possible. So they need help in
the
form of reduced expenses and/or new work and retraining if necessary and
possible. Ideally they also will find work to do that helps out during
the pandemic, even if they cannot be paid for it and may need simply to
volunteer. Or they need to be able to get paying work at something
not otherwise being
done or not being done enough, or they need to give more leisure (or an
otherwise eased workload)
to people still working, by helping them do that work for fair pay. In
some cases, to promote fairness and shared risk and burden in a
pandemic, those displaced from unnecessary work that requires group
proximity, should help out with necessary work that requires some
proximity, such as helping stock grocery shelves, provide family child
care for people who have to work outside the home (or who need help with
childcare while working from home), etc.
Notice
also that pandemics are disruptive in proportion, not only to the
probability of people congregating even if they know they are ill, but
to the length of time between infection and detection, because isolation
has to allow for unknown contagion by people who would not knowingly
congregate with others if they knew they were a carrier. In other
words, if we could 1) know immediately when someone is ill, and 2) count
on them self-isolating, disruptions would be less because work done by,
and/or serving, healthy people together would not be problematic.But
insofar as people can be contagious before they know they are ill, and
insofar as ill people feel they have to work even if ill, pandemics
requiring untargeted, nonspecific, imprecise social distancing are more
economically disruptive.
One
of the early efforts in the United States to contain the COVID-19 pandemic was to
try to minimize or eliminate people from going to work with others when
they know they are ill, by giving everyone sick leave pay so that they
can afford to miss work and self-isolate. Many other countries
already
had that policy in place (and so the bigger problem for them was people
congregating without yet knowing they were infected and contagious).
Sick leave is one economic mechanism to minimize the economic
harms of
pandemics over and above those caused by death and incapacitation of
workers. Another, partially economic, partially social, partially
medical method to try to allow the economy to function but preventing
contagion was the monitoring of passengers for fevers or other
signs of COVID-19 infection before they could board flights. But
this only
prevented those with clear signs or symptoms from infecting others after
they were detected, not before (e.g., while waiting in line at the
airport to have their temperature taken), and it did nothing to prevent
contagious people without signs or symptoms yet from infecting the
others on the flight. That is the problem with a lag between
contagious
infection and actual detection of the disease, as mentioned before.
The
reason I am writing this is because there are other such mechanisms
that are needed and possible to overcome the primarily economic harms of
pandemics, as opposed to the medical, physical ones. As of this
writing, economic disruptions are at least as big a concern as are the
medical ones, and economic solutions need to be found while medical ones
are still being sought, and may need to be found even after medical
ones are. If a cure
or prevention of the spread for pandemic were found, the economy could
get back to normal if disruptions are properly prevented from being
fatal to businesses. But such a cure or vaccine is not
expected to be able to be employed soon, and so people need to be
protected and treated medically and also financially or economically.
Economic Solutions and the Rationale Behind Them
The
first principle should be understanding that we are all in this
together and that it is somewhat pure chance not only who will become
infected by the disease, but whose kind of work will be become disrupted
by isolation or 'social distancing' needed to combat the spread of it.
To some extent there is
a reversal of fortune between those most successful in normal times and
those most adversely affected by pandemics, not just because
those who
have gained the most (or who have the most invested to begin or to
continue to gain) have the most to lose, but because much wealth
accrues from crowds in stadiums, arenas, theaters, restaurants, etc.
and/or from an aggregation of people working in the same location
together. Those jobs are the first affected by pandemics requiring
social distance to combat.
[Related
to this, I must say here that I am perplexed by the suspension of
major professional sporting events, given that most of the revenue for
them comes from TV,
rather than arena/stadium crowds. I don’t see, for example, why the NCAA
basketball
tournament, i.e., “March Madness” was canceled, as opposed to just being
played in empty arenas. While that might be somewhat weird for
players and fans watching on TV, it would not be that weird because 1)
many fans turn off the sound while watching a sport on TV anyway so they
won’t have to listen to announcers they don’t like, and 2) players who
grew up playing on playgrounds, tennis courts, golf courses, etc. by
themselves played perfectly well for years without people watching,
cheering, or exhorting them to try harder, etc. 3) Players also
generally practice in relatively empty arenas or stadiums. It is
not like you can't catch a football or tackle someone, throw or hit a
baseball, shoot a puck or kick a ball into a net, or make a basket if
there is no crowd.]
Once
it is realized that we are all in this together and that chance plays a
role in whose work is disrupted and whose is not, we should be willing
to ‘self-insure’ each other as a society so that no one is more
economically unreasonably harmed by a disruption than we can
collectively prevent. Insurance works by people who are not harmed
paying in large part for the harms or damage done to those who are
harmed. Normally that requires that everyone insured pays premiums, which are used to pay for
those who collect benefits from authorized, hopefully legitimate, claims. We don't know
in advance who will be harmed and who will not be. In the case of
pandemics the 'self-insurance' will be in large part
retroactive, in that the plan was not available beforehand and so
premiums were not previously collected from which benefits could be paid.
Instead, other sources of funding the benefits will have to be
utilized after the harms are determined. To some extent we know ahead of times which businesses
will be harmed by 'social distancing' and which will not, but we don't
know when pandemics or epidemics will strike or which populations or
subsets of populations will be affected (most). Moreover the kind
of self-insurance for large scale disruptions includes disasters besides
medical or biological ones, which may affect different people. I
believe that societal economic self-insurance 'after the fact' is a
fair and reasonable way to prevent tragedies from economic disruptions.
Theoretically (and this is theoretically only because
extremely difficult to put into practice, but the basic principle is most important
to understand because it needs to underlie any practical attempted financial remedy), the economy would, in a purely financial or monetary way,
not be
harmed at all by a pandemic if people paid for the products and services
they would have purchased but couldn't and didn't. (This is apart from deaths of any
key person whose skills are necessary and could not easily be replaced
by someone else, and it is apart from the loss or postponement of
innovations that would improve productivity. I am talking now only
about loss of work by those
who are idled by social distancing and by actual temporary illness during the pandemic, not by death or permanent inability
to return to their work.) That is because the money
lost by those unable to work is money saved by
those who would have otherwise paid for their services or
products. It is not that there is less money in the society during
a pandemic, but
that money is not circulating to the extent it was. It circulates
among fewer people -- those still able to work and those with incomes
guaranteed by people or institutions that still have money available to
pay it, such as Social Security or loan repayments, retirement funds,
etc. And it is not circulating in ways
it normally needs to in order for all people to be included in the
economy and for products and services to be produced, traded, and
utilized. So if people who would have traveled but couldn't
because of the pandemic still paid the airlines for flights they didn't
take and paid the hotels for rooms they didn't use, and restaurants for
food they didn't order, paid for the gas they didn't use, the 'economy'
would go on as it does normally, and everyone would be able to pay their
bills as they had prior to the pandemic. Of course, the obvious
problem
with that is it seems stupid and pointless to pay for something you
don't get or use.
However, in actual fact that is what insurance
premiums do for things where insurance is available, and particularly
where it is common. Insurance premiums paid by those who don't
have to make claims or collect benefits pay for the benefits of those who
have insured harms befall them. They pay for things never ordered and
never received by the insured person who never makes a claim. If
this were flight or hotel cancellation insurance, it would basically be
what I just described in theory -- paying for trips one never
takes. My standard joke when returning a rental car for which I
took out (additional) rental insurance is "Since I didn't have any
accidents, can I get my insurance premium back please, since I didn't
use the insurance?" That would make sense only if premiums were
simply a pre-payment that covered the cost all by itself of any damage
from an accident. But that isn't what premiums are -- they are
one's share of money pooled to pay for work done and replacement items for the people who do
have accidents or insured losses. If you don't have an accident or loss, you are paying for a
service you don't use. If, during a pandemic, people paid for
hotel rooms, airline trips, etc. which they didn't utilize, it would be
the same thing, and actually less expensive because it would not require
paying the incomes of insurance company investors and employees besides
paying for the work needed.
Now I realize "economic disruption
self-insurance" by a country is a strange enough idea, but it is far
more
likely to happen or make sense to people than telling everyone to pay
for the things they would have bought if they could have, but didn't
buy because they now couldn't or shouldn't -- although at least one
sports club of some sort has asked people to continue paying their
monthly membership fees, even though the facility is closed, so he can
pay his employees, and many or all have obliged. But I realize
this cannot likely be successfully required or even happen voluntarily
to any great extent, but it would
be the simplest way to keep the economy going, and it does show that
the economic problem of monetary disruption and loss of unnecessary
goods and services is in some way artificial (as opposed to the actual diminished supply or loss of necessary goods
and services). And it
would be the fairest way to pay for the losses of revenue by businesses
that couldn't operate, because it would replace the money they lost
from their inability to provide services or products with the money
saved by those who would have otherwise spent it. The money
lost would be paid by the money gained or kept; i.e., the money not spent which would have been spent. What would be
lost by paying for a trip to Disney World one doesn't take, compared
with paying for a trip one does take, is, of course the enjoyment of
Disney World. But if that joy was replaced by a different one,
perhaps a free or relatively, equally great one or better, during the
social distancing
time, it wouldn't matter, and it would keep the travel industry open for
future trips. In this last regard, the point of paying for
something you don't use now is to allow it to survive for when you can
and do want to use it in the future, once the (pandemic) disruption has
passed. One can recover from not having a convenience or
luxury one doesn't really need; but it is far more difficult to recover
from loss of a career, health, home, or business due to lack of income
that was
needed to pay a mortgage, purchase food, medicine, personal and
environmental hygiene, or keep a company able to operate or recover from
having been (temporarily) suspended. If children, for example,
enjoy putting puzzles together, watching TV, doing science experiments,
reading good books from the Internet, communicating and doing things
together online (like playing music together and recording it) they
haven't really lost anything by not going to Disney World. And, of
course, it would be even better if Disney provided free entertainment
for children in the duration that costs them little or nothing to
provide, such as on TV or allowing free downloads of past movies, to
anyone who pays for their Disney World visit, airline ticket not taken
and hotel room not used.
And remember, this
is different from a very real problem of not having sufficient necessary
goods and services available, such as medical care or important flights
or other services, goods, or events, in an acute
pandemic, that no amount of money would be able to alleviate anyway in
the time frame necessary. I am only talking about the monetary
economic parts of the economy. There are really two issues in the
pandemic: the monetary circulation one and unavoidable losses of goods
and services that cannot be reconstituted, replenished, or made up for
by future, post-pandemic efforts, due to disabilities caused by the
pandemic, loss of life, or loss of perishable goods necessary for
time-sensitive productivity. For example, if there is cattle feed
available but no money to purchase it, cows can still be fed by the feed
being donated by those who have it or by someone else's paying for it
on behalf of farmers through gifts, loans, etc.; but if a pandemic wipes
out cattle workers, cattle, feed, or those who produce feed, then that
diminishes the future availability of dairy or beef products. If
seed for crops is not available at the proper time, those crops will be
lost for that year. In this regard money is different from
material and biological things because the money doesn't
disappear. Money in the stock market is often said to disappear
during downturns, but it is not really money
disappearing. It, like all "market values" changes, is an artificial
price change (in this case, decrease), based on most recent sales that
may or may not be indicative of future sales -- depending on all kinds
of outside factors rather than on a change in the quality, usefulness,
or meaningfulness of the thing itself. See "The Meaning of Market Prices."
What happens in any large scale economic disruption, whether due to a
pandemic or recession or depression, widespread natural disaster, or
anything else, is that money
pools up in ways that do not line up with unused, available labor and
work that needs to be done. It is a misalignment of money and
labor, not a deficiency of people to do the work (apart from deaths and
permanent disabilities caused by the disruption), but lack of a
mechanism to bring together those who could do the work, those who need
the work, and those who can pay for it. It is not dissimilar to the
problem of barter where someone with an extra cow needs a horse, but the
person with the extra horse doesn't need a cow. If the person
with the extra horse can find
an intermediary person who wants the horse and can trade something for
it -- say, an inherited piano that is never played -- that would be
wanted by the person with the extra cow, the three-way trade can occur
to let the person get rid of his extra horse in exchange for the piano
and then trade the piano for the cow he wanted, while the person who had
the extra cow gets the piano he wants. It will all work
out. In a fully functioning monetary
economy there is not that exact same problem because money serves as a
universal
intermediary trading medium. So if the person can sell his extra
cow to
someone who pays him money for it that he then uses to buy the horse
with; and that person can then use that money, if he wants, to buy a
used piano. Or GM has cars they want to sell but NBC doesn't need all
those cars, though they have TV shows that GM doesn't really need.
But NBC can sell advertising time to GM who then gains customers who
want to buy their cars they saw advertised during a comedy or a sporting
event they watched for free on NBC.
But the same sort of trading problem does arise in a monetary
economy when people with the needs don't have money though they have
services or products to offer to people who have money but don't need
(or can't use) those particular products or services. In normal
circumstances money and labor become aligned (to
various
degrees if at all) over time as businesses try to adapt to meet new
demands (such as
Internet, large flat screen TVs, computers, cell phones, grocery
stores, lawn care services, new sports, new styles of music, social
media "influencers", etc.) and people seek work, or develop new
skills, they know they
can make money from to meet their needs. In some cases that means
borrowing money to begin with that will be paid back over time as labor
and money realign.
But in a major, acute disruption, normal
channels for
getting money and labor realigned take too long and people can lose
their homes, health care, food, etc., and even their lives, in the
duration. Recent news reports, for example, told about farmers
destroying food they could not sell or store, while people are unable to
buy the food they need -- because they don't have money, not because
there isn't, or couldn't be, food. The same sort of disruptions
happen when new inventions render some jobs or incomes obsolete or
seriously reduced. The advent of fifty zillion cable channels and
Internet
streaming entertainment subtracts from NBC's viewing audience and makes
GM's advertising on NBC less rewarding to them, disrupting to at least
some extent this trading circle. It has also meant loss of common,
shared information, and the social cohesion that is engendered by
it. And when the Soviet Union collapsed,
that fostered the closing of military bases considered no longer
necessary, and disrupted the economy of the areas who depended on them
for sales. In a fictional kind of case, if the Star Trek
transporter were invented and
available inexpensively, it would probably destroy the automobile
and airline industries and collapse the economy unless some way could be
found to put
back into the trading system all those who work in those industries,
supply them, etc. If all diseases could be prevented, it
would put the medical establishment out of business. We are good
at including into the economic system unemployed people by putting them
to work when new needs are discovered or created, but we are horrible at
knowing how to keep people in the economic system when their work is no
longer needed or (in the case of the pandemic, cannot be done).
We know how to distribute work easily enough, but not how to distribute
leisure. We know how to combine work with money easily enough, but
not how to combine money with leisure, except over time by decreasing
the hours of the work week or by increasing paid vacation time, number
of paid holidays, etc as fewer hours of human labor are needed to meet
human needs and desires. This is the same problem that we will
have as human labor is able to be replaced by robots, since the work of
the displaced humans will not be needed, but they still need to be able
to trade to earn the necessities, conveniences, and luxuries being
produced. Ideally as robots replace humans, those humans would
share the work of humans who robots cannot replace, and everyone would
have more leisure. But that is difficult to work out in practice
because some work is too difficult or too time-consuming to learn.
In some
cases, we even have difficulty putting people to work to meet needs,
such as research for rare ("orphan") diseases or labor intensive
services for poor people, even in a healthy, vibrant, normally
functioning economy there are no normal trade ways to channel some labor
where necessary, because the scale of the work needed does not match the
scale of the number of people who need it and the money they have to
pay for it. In those cases, it requires charitable monetary
donations,
voluntary labor, and/or taxation if they are to be done at all.
And in some cases it is difficult to figure out
how to monetize a worthy service to make it profitable. Sometimes
the reverse is true, and a fairly ultimately worthless, or even harmful,
service or product can make a lot of money. In an ideal
economic
society, however, all needs and benefits that can be produced will be
available and distributed to all who need them or who would benefit from
them, and in turn those who received the benefits will contribute
benefit for others by their own production of useful products or
services. And there will be mechanisms that allow that to work
through simple monetary exchanges (or sometimes barter) where possible,
and through more convoluted or
complicated ones when not. In such a society or even in a normal
economically functioning society, large scale economic disruptions which
are
not easily restored before permanent physical harm is done, need to
employ non-standard methods to get labor employed to meet the needs of
everyone to the greatest possible extent. When money gets
misaligned with goods and services and monetary trade
cannot produce and properly distribute the goods or services people want
or need, non-trade or non-monetary
mechanisms are utilized to try to bridge the gap; barter, volunteered
labor, taxation, charitable gifts and donations (whether of money or
goods), insurance, lotteries and other forms
of gambling all separate to some degree or the flow of money from the
flow of labor and products of labor.
Insurance itself is a form of gambling. Another form is a lottery
or a raffle. In a lottery tickets are bought to try to win money;
in a raffle tickets are bought to win some specific service or
product. And there is an old joke that particularly illustrates
how something like a raffle separates the exchange of money from the
exchange of goods and services. A farmer's mule dies and he doesn't have
enough money to buy a new one. A new mule would cost him
$500. And he needs a mule. So he has raffle tickets printed
up that he sells for $2 each and they are raffle tickets to win a
mule. He just doesn't say that the mule that will be won is his
dead mule. He sells 1000 tickets, and buys his new mule, leaving
him a profit of nearly $1500 over and above the cost of the mule and the
cost of having the raffle tickets printed. Of course, when the
winner comes to pick up his mule, he balks at the fact that it is
dead. The farmer doesn't want the winner to be unhappy, so he
gives him his back his $2. For my purposes here, we could remove
the absurd humorous part and say that the farmer bought two new mules
with the proceeds of the raffle and gave one of them to the
winner. Either way, a lot of money has exchanged that didn't give
the buyers anything but the hope or fantasy of getting a mule for $2, and didn't require the farmer to do any real labor
to earn.
Basically, there are instances possible in a monetary economic
system which separate the flow of money from the flow of equivalent goods and
services. It is easy to see that fraud, welshing, bankruptcy,
etc. are ways labor can be done without getting money for it, and it is
easy to see that theft is a way for money to change hands without giving
up a product or labor. It is not as obvious that there are many
other ways to separate money from the equivalent labor, ways we often
take for granted as not doing that and as being fair or normal, whether
it is not paying people what their labor should really be worth to you
because you can exploit their being in dire circumstances that make them
agree to be paid little, whether it is losing or making money via an
investment, or a loan at too high or too low an interest rate for the
changing value of money through time (inflation or deflation), whether
it is through being able to afford to buy in bulk or economize in some
other way, whether it is through artificial loan instruments like the
mortgage-backed securities and collateralized debt obligations of the
subprime mortgage crisis that fostered the great recession beginning in
2007 and blossoming in 2008. Even normal commerce can lead to
dislocations of money and labor if money is hoarded instead of spent, or
if great amounts of money are wasted in any of various ways that don't
get it back into the hands of those who need or do useful and important
work.
Since
the flow of money doesn't always coincide naturally with the flow of
good and useful products and services, it seems to me that since that is
often harmful and yet accepted, that it should be at least as accepted
to separate the two in ways that actually benefit society in fair and
reasonable ways. And one of those would be some fair,
effective, efficient, and reasonable form or other of retroactive
widespread economic disruption insurance that is targeted to benefit
only those actually harmed by the economic disruption, which the
recently passed 2 trillion dollar 'rescue' or 'bailout' package does not
do. It will pay some people or businesses too much and others too
little. It will pay some people whose incomes have not been
affected at all the same amount it pays those who lost their income
totally during the social distancing period. The people and
businesses that are beneficiaries of the money should be those that
deserve it and the amount should be fair and reasonable. The
places from which the money is taken should be fair and reasonable
too. That all needs to be worked out in detail and may need some
corrections over time. The two trillion dollar government
bailout or 'rescue' plan is too blunt an instrument insufficiently
benefiting those who need and deserve it and unfairly and unreasonably
putting it into the hands of those who don't. Plus it is not clear
whether it will be taken from those who made or saved money because of
social distancing from those who lost it, which seems to me to be at
least one important consideration.
Pandemics Magnify the Problems of 'Normal' Economic Disruptions
Disruptions that put people outside the economy happen to unemployed
people during normal times,
and many of them have at least some sort of safety net, but others don't
and are too often ignored. Once the same problem reaches the
magnitude and number of people affected by it in a pandemic, the victims
can no longer be ignored. But they shouldn't have been ignored
before when their numbers were smaller either. Serious or large
scale pathologies in any
kind of system often
shed light on the normal functioning within the system by exposing their
weaknesses and
flaws that
were previously largely unnoticed by most people. In the
case of economic systems, for example, people in government and in the
general population are often unaware of the failings of normal trade
to include people whose plights are recognized or understood only by
them and the relatively few who advocate for them. When only a few are
affected, their problems are often dismissed as unavoidable or likely
their own fault, but once far more are affected, particularly people who
are clearly good, deserving people, the problem cannot be dismissed in
those ways.
Failure of the normal means of realigning labor and money requires using mechanisms outside the normal economic ways of distributing money, in order to shift resources and money to do the most good during, and immediately after, the
disruptions of the pandemic. We often do this voluntarily in localized,
short term emergencies, as explained in “The Intersection of Ethics and Economics”,
and/or by invoking pre-established ‘declared emergency’ laws.
Farmers throughout the country often retroactively self-insure in a broad sense by
sending feed to areas affected by excessive drought or flooding, etc.,
knowing that if or when the circumstances are reversed, they will be
helped.
Many people volunteer their labor to help clear snow or fallen trees or
other debris, use their 4-wheel drive vehicles or boats to transport
their fellow citizens, stock up or serve at food kitchens, etc.
State
governments invoke emergency decrees which, among other things, prohibit
price gouging, hoarding, and which may require rationing of some things
to insure the most people can get what they need,
etc. Unfortunately, not everyone is fair, reasonable, kind, or
generous. Businesses with lobbyists, for example, apparently lined
up to have money for their companies or industries favored in bailout
funds, whether they need or deserve it or not. Selfishness and
greed serve instead of kindness and generosity.
[Whether
some of the good mechanisms outside the normal ones should remain in
play or be expanded to cover the 'normal' failures in the system, after
the pandemic is an
ethical, social, economic, political decision for later. E.g.,
during
WW II on the home front women were able to do jobs, because of the
emergency need, they were previously excluded from, and often then
subsequently excluded from again -- except that they now had not only
more of a desire to hold such jobs and other kinds of difficult jobs,
but demonstrable knowledge they could do them successfully. That
added
to women’s employment opportunities eventually, although in the United
States women and minorities still lag behind white males in economic
opportunities in many ways in general. The point is that pandemics
and
other emergencies sometimes offer insights for fairer and more
productive economic practices during normal times, and those should be
seen from a broader perspective not only during the emergency but prior
to emergencies and subsequent to their successful ending. World
War II led to the GI Bill of Rights that allowed many soldiers to go to
college who otherwise would not have been able to, and made the economy
eventually more productive. But today we have homeless vets on the
streets who clearly need more or a different kind of help. They
deserve it for their service and what their service cost them; and it
would be better for all of us if they could succeed and be contributing
members of society instead of having to squander their potential talents
barely existing.]
Self-insuring
against the economic disruptions of pandemics or other large scale
disasters or changes (such as when many U.S. military bases closed after
the Soviet Union broke up)
requires 1) as far as possible putting to work in necessary fields
those who are displaced from their normal work, particularly those
displaced from work that is in some sense arguably less necessary, 2)
giving financial assistance to those who cannot find paid work while
their own field is disrupted, and 3) putting disrupted industries
(schools, sports, factory work, etc.) as much as possible into a kind of
economic suspended animation that allows them to be revived when the
pandemic abates or ends. If possible to avoid as a society, no one
should (permanently) lose their health, life, home, business or anything
else of importance because of a temporary disruption of
their work and economic trade that is no fault of their own. And no one
should remain idle from work that needs to be done and cannot be put off
till later -- such as more
personalized child care for children who would otherwise be in school,
and individualized tutoring (particularly by remote means where
possible), working in a plant to make masks, while wearing masks to stay
safe while making others, or helping put up temporary hospital units,
or doing any of the other numerous medical or ‘pre-medical’ things that
could be taught to lay people or health care students -- the hospital
and medical equivalents of
Habitat for Humanity model. Keep necessary productivity going as
much
as possible by utilizing those people whose normal less necessary work
is disrupted, and
sort out all
the payment issues as much as possible first, but later if necessary to
correct or modify them. Mobilize the work force and existing
manufacturing facilities as much as possible and reasonable as one does
during a military war for survival, where in WWII people and auto plants
and other industries were put to work making tanks, planes, other
military vehicles, etc.
As of this writing during the COVID-19 pandemic
in the United States, many people are volunteering help of all sorts and
volunteering their labor wherever it is needed and can be used.
At least one restaurant in New York City is feeding everyone who cannot
afford food, and the owner said he will do that as long as he is
able. People like him need money channeled to him so he can buy
the food he needs to serve to others. A disruption in the flow of
money and the normal trading mechanisms of society should not cause
people to starve to death when there is food available and people
available to
prepare and distribute it. In another example, one including
innovation, a company that makes scuba gear has converted to making home
ventilators. One or more car manufacturers offered to retool to make
ventilators.
Some clothing manufactures are converting to making masks. Some
people figured out a design to make ventilator parts or other needed
medical equipment using a 3D printer, and have made the plans available
for free to everyone with a 3D printer. All kinds of people
whose work is idled by the economic disruption are putting their time,
energy, and sometimes expertise, into trying to reduce the physical
harms and important material deprivations of the pandemic.
Society should ensure they are not
economically deprived now or later, especially if they had to use their
own money to do the good they are contributing. Financial
institutions are suspending or modifying rent, mortgage, car loan and
other loan repayments, in some cases as much as they can, to help people
have money for
food or medicine.
Yet, in some cases there is an unnecessary system failure, as pointed
out earlier, for example, when farmers have to destroy food they cannot
sell or store for later sale, while some people are having to do without
food because they don't have money to buy it. Permanent losses
shouldn't be allowed to happen just because the economic trading system
is either flawed or temporarily disrupted.
The
third point above, about putting disrupted industries and businesses in
'economic suspended animation' includes some attempt to make up for
lost productivity
and/or revenue where possible, and to sustain people in those businesses
after the pandemic where necessary because some losses due to lost time
cannot be made up and are permanent. Some losses can be made up.
E.g.,
sporting events can be rescheduled for after the pandemic, missed school
days can be made up, lost manufacturing productivity can sometimes be
made up by overtime production, etc. But this might mean paying
people
like teachers, in advance while they are not working, the money they
would be paid while not working during the summer. In other words,
pay them now for work
they
will do later and just swap paid vacation time and work time.
But
some losses cannot be made up, such as permanent harms caused by
unavailability of medical resources, losses of perishable items that
cannot be sold during the pandemic (one major flower distributor in
Birmingham has given away all his fresh flowers so that they don't go to
waste even though he cannot remain open to sell them), incomes based on
work that cannot be
doubled up on later, such as restaurant work or nursing care, hotel
bookings, airline wages for flights not made, or any kind of job that is
exhausting during normal times. Even rescheduling some sporting
events
can cause irreparable disruptions, such as rescheduling the Olympics
for two years later, since athletes at their peak presently may not be
as competitive then, which causes them a loss, though what they lose is
potentially gained by others instead (in terms of victories, but
not
necessarily in terms of individual records, such as winning medals in
consecutive Olympics or most career Olympic medals, etc). What
constitutes a permanent loss that is fair to be compensated for is open
to individual evidence and reasoning, much like distribution of
reparations to businesses harmed by an oil spill, though without
as much red tape if possible.
But money is something that doesn’t necessarily have to be lost, as pointed out throughout Ethical and Philosophical Foundations of Economics.
There should be a relationship between money and labor that is not
always met by existing business practices or by normal government
practices that try to correct some of them. One example is the loss of
perishable food by those who have it while others may be going hungry
because they don’t have a means to buy or get food, such as free or
reduced cost school lunches. If ways can be found to distribute the
food before it spoils to those who need it, the payment for that food
can be worked out somehow. The important thing is to get the work done,
and then paid for as soon as possible, not necessarily at the time of
the transaction if that cannot be worked out by that time. One example
is that some telecommunication companies are providing free Internet
services (such as unlimited data, or connections for students) during
the pandemic to help people stay connected and to help students still be in school. That is an admirable act
and a great example of individuals and companies voluntarily
contributing what they know they can that might not have been thought of
by a governmental or other centralized planning agency, and that might
have been less fair (or at least less palatable) to require than to be
done voluntarily.
Oppositely,
price gouging and unfair profiteering should not be allowed where
possible to prevent. As of this writing, Amazon, eBay, and other
companies have tried to stop that by suspending the sale of overpriced
items, especially those that were hoarded in attempts to corner markets
for them, as in the case of the people who bought up all the hand
sanitizer they could get in order to sell it for ten or more times the
price later. Even just hoarding needs to be prevented where
possible, in
order to keep those who buy early from getting more than they need for
themselves while denying others access to necessities because of it.
Sam’s Club, for example, limited purchases of cases of bottled
water to
two per customer when a run on bottled water started. Some
companies
are limiting the purchases of other items, such as toilet paper, that
people have been panic buying. This is clearly a suspension of the
normal business practices of selling people whatever they are willing
to buy at the price being charged.
Moreover,
clearly some businesses profiting early, but fairly, from the pandemic,
need to save those profits for later when they cannot sell what people
have already stocked up on and don’t any longer need to purchase for a
while. The current runs on toilet paper and hand sanitizer, for
example, generate legitimate profits that those manufacturers will need
to ‘coast on’ after the pandemic because people won’t need to buy toilet
paper and hand sanitizer until their current supplies run out.
One cartoon gave a future news report something like "December 12,
2062: Tom Evans
yesterday used the last of the toilet paper his grandparents had bought
for the coronavirus pandemic in 2020." And
although the rate of use of toilet paper may be a constant, the rate of
use of hand sanitizer will probably diminish after the pandemic passes.
It will take people the normal usual time to use up toilet paper, but
will take them longer to run through all the bottles of hand sanitizer
later. The Sam's Club I use that was extremely busy two weeks ago
with wall to wall people with full carts, was almost empty two days ago
and the few people who were just getting a few things. One doesn't need
to keep buying non-perishable goods one has already bought in excess.
In
short, we as a nation during this emergency need to do what we can to
prevent the most harm caused by both the virus and the disruptions of
work caused by social isolation to contain and end the contagion.
That
will require volunteerism, innovation, and ways to reasonably and
fairly distribute benefits and burdens outside the normal economic means
of trade and business. We should be willing to countenance fair
and reasonable methods of distributing money during and after the
pandemic, even if they go against the normal ways we do, and have done,
business and trade.
|